Skip to content

About PERC

All Areas of Focus

All Research

Donate

Why Economic Growth is Good for the Environment

Hoover Digest
2004 No.3 Summer

Cooling the Global Warming Debate:

By Terry L. Anderson

In the March 2004 issue of Scientific American, National Aeronautics and Space Administration
global-warming expert James Hansen notes that greenhouse gas emissions and global-warming projections
are “consistently pessimistic.” Hansen suggests that projections do not take into account the lower
carbon dioxide and methane emissions that have resulted from technological advancements. He explains
that the lower carbon dioxide emissions result from increased energy efficiency following the energy
crisis in the 1970s and the lower methane emissions, from technological changes in agriculture.

Hansen’s essay concludes on an optimistic note, saying “the main elements [new technologies] required to halt climate change
have come into being with remarkable rapidity.” This statement would not have surprised economist Julian Simon. He saw
the “ultimate resource” to be the human mind and believed it to be best motivated by market forces.

Because of a combination of market forces and technological innovations, we are not running out of natural resources.
As a resource becomes more scarce, prices increase, thus encouraging development of cheaper alternatives and technological
innovations. Just as fossil fuel replaced scarce whale oil, its use will be reduced by new technology and alternative
fuel sources.

Market forces also cause economic growth, which in turn leads to environmental improvements. Put simply, poor people are
willing to sacrifice clean water and air, healthy forests, and wildlife habitat for economic growth. But as their incomes
rise above subsistence, “economic growth helps to undo the damage done in earlier years,” says economist Bruce Yandle.
“If economic growth is good for the environment, policies that stimulate growth ought to be good for the environment.”

The link between greenhouse gas emissions and economic prosperity is no different. Using data from the United States,
Professor Robert McCormick finds that “higher GDP reduces total net [greenhouse gas] emissions.”

He goes a step further by performing the complex task of estimating net U.S. carbon emissions. This requires subtracting
carbon sequestration (long-term storage of carbon in soil and water) from carbon emissions. Think of it this way: When
you build a house, the wood in it stores carbon. In a poor country that wood would have been burned to cook supper or
to provide heat, thus releasing carbon into the atmosphere. McCormick shows that economic growth in the United States
has increased carbon sequestration in many ways, including improved methods of storing waste, increased forest coverage,
and greater agricultural productivity that reduces the acreage of cultivated land.

Because rich economies sequester more carbon than poor ones, stored carbon must be subtracted from emissions to
determine an economy’s net addition to greenhouse gas emissions. McCormick’s data show that “rich countries take
more carbon out of the air than poorer ones” and that “the growth rate of net carbon emission per person will
soon be negative in the United States.” Put differently—richer may well be cooler.

Global-warming policy analysts agree that greenhouse gas regulations such as those proposed at Kyoto would have
negative impacts on the economy. Therefore, as McCormick warns, we should take great care that regulations in
the name of global warming “not kill the goose that lays the golden eggs.”

This essay was published as part of the Hoover
Institution Weekly Essay series, which is
distributed by Knight Ridder/Tribune, April 29, 2004.

New from the Hoover Press is You Have to Admit It’s
Getting Better: From Economic Prosperity to Environmental Quality
, edited by Terry L. Anderson.

Date
Topics
Related Content