Skip to content

About PERC

All Areas of Focus

All Research

Donate

What’s wrong with the global oil market?

Recent developments in domestic energy production have shifted the political debate about energy independence. Yet as the discussion focuses on finding a desirable mix of American energy sources, policy decisions must account for a global oil market distorted by the interventions of foreign governments.

Some may think this doesn’t matter because the domestic oil boom offers the United States a chance to reclaim the title of the world’s largest oil producer. Estimates suggest that there are more than seven billion barrels of oil in shale formations in the Dakotas and Montana alone. If more federal lands were opened to exploration, there is no doubt Americans could soon lose the need to import oil.

Yet even under this welcome scenario, America would not be truly energy independent. Increased domestic production, however beneficial, cannot insulate the price Americans pay at the pump from the global price of oil. Whether extracted in North Dakota or Saudi Arabia, oil is a commodity priced in global markets. Increased domestic production will not diminish the role played by the OPEC (Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries) cartel.

Securing America’s Future Energy (SAFE), an organization that seeks to protect American national and economic security through reduced oil dependence, asked us to survey the literature on the global oil market. We reviewed hundreds of articles from the economics and policy literature, as well as dozens of experts’ congressional testimony. This review identified three important aspects of the oil market that policy makers should keep in mind.

First, the oil market is far from the free market of economics textbooks. OPEC, which came to prominence in the 1970s, is what MIT professor and oil expert Morris Adelman termed a “clumsy cartel.” When it is effective, it has an impact. OPEC works to restrict supply. Saudi Arabia’s announcement in January 2013 that it had cut production five percent in December 2012 led oil prices for February delivery to climb 72 cents per barrel. Monopolies drive up prices and lower productivity and misallocate resources. One study estimated the cost of OPEC to the U.S. economy was as much as $500 billion in 2008.

The price volatility caused by OPEC harms American interests no matter how the price moves. When OPEC forces the price of oil higher, Americans have transferred a premium to OPEC nations beyond what the competitive market price of oil would have been. When OPEC suffers a collapse, the price at times has fallen so low as to disincentivize alternatives to oil, as well as new, higher-cost oil supplies.

Second, the stability of OPEC itself depends heavily on non-market factors. OPEC functions poorly when its members are fighting wars with each other (as Iran and Iraq did between 1980 and 1988). It functions more effectively when it has support from the outside, as it did when the Nixon Administration used higher oil prices as a means of subsidizing allies like the Shah of Iran without asking Congress to authorize sending a check.

Third, most of the world’s oil reserves outside the United States are controlled by government-owned oil companies such as Venezuela’s PDVSA or the Saudi Arabian Oil Company (Saudi Aramco). They behave quite differently from profit-maximizing firms. Unlike in the United States, where mineral rights are often privately owned, in the rest of the world mineral rights belong to governments. Autocrats use control of their nations’ oil resources as a political tool.

While it has long been fashionable to bash “big oil,” the largest private-sector international oil companies had access to just 15 percent of world reserves in 2010. They are primarily developers of reserves owned by governments. Not surprisingly, given the risky nature of the business and the instability of many resource-rich governments, returns are generally lower than in lines of business not dominated by governments. The real players in oil markets are governments, not profit-driven businesses.

There has long been debate about what U.S. policy makers should do about the global oil market. There are problems with many government solutions. For example, the Obama Administration’s push into green energy has been marred by crony capitalism and big bets on failed technologies, the latest in a long series of bad investments by politically controlled bureaucracies. Only the naïve would be surprised that command-and-control efforts turn out to be little more than political payoffs.

Moreover, green groups are happy to see higher prices for energy sources they dislike, such as oil. Much as the Nixon Administration saw OPEC as a means of accomplishing foreign policy goals, green groups want higher oil prices to push consumers toward their preferred energy sources. Because it would be unpopular to directly propose higher prices, like Nixon, they prefer indirect means of achieving their goals.

There’s no magic solution to these problems. Oil-producing nations are entitled to do as they wish with their oil. Neither OPEC nor the political nature of oil resource owners is going away. We need a vigorous debate among those who believe in the virtues of competitive markets about how to deal with persistent imperfections in the market for our most important energy resource. Accepting the status quo risks ceding this issue to crony capitalists and often-hostile foreign governments extracting enormous rents from the American economy. 

Roger Meiners is the Goolsby-Rosenthal Chair in Economics and Law at the University of Texas at Arlington.

Andrew Morriss is D. Paul Jones, Jr. & Charlene A. Jones Chairholder in Law and Professor of Business at the University of Alabama. They are authors of Competition in Global Oil Markets: A Meta-Analysis and Review.

Date
Topics
Related Content
  • PERC Reports Winter 2024

    This special issue of PERC Reports explores creative ideas to address the conservation challenges of the Pacific Northwest.

  • A Coastal Comeback

    It’s been more than a century since sea otters called the coasts of Oregon and Northern California home. Can they be brought back to the region without alienating fishermen?

  • Kelp Wanted

    Can cultivating a taste for purple sea urchin help restore America's underwater forests?